CHAPTER IV. OBJECTIONS TO THE SCHEME.

Previous

I now propose to consider objections which may be raised to the proposed scheme.

I anticipate opposition from those who object to all forms of State Ownership or State Management.

The late Lord Avebury was one of the most prominent opponents of nationalisation, and his views are set out in his book “On Municipal and National Trading.”[6]

Mr. Edwin A. Pratt has written several books on the subject and has recently collected all the arguments up to date against State Ownership in his book, “The Case against Railway Nationalisation,”[7] In this book examples are given of the experience of foreign countries and the Colonies where railways have been taken over by the State.

Other writers who have advocated the retention of our present system, and are quoted with approval by Lord Avebury, are the following:—

Messrs. G. Foxwell and T. C. Farrer (now Lord Farrer), in “Express Trains, English and Foreign.” (1889);

Mr. W. M. Acworth, in “The Railways and the Traders”;

Mr. H. R. Meyer, in “Government Regulation of Railway Rates,” and in “Railway Rates”;

and Lord Farrer and Mr. Giffin, in “The State in its Relation to Trade.”

On the other side, the following, among other advocates of railway nationalisation have shown the great advantages to be anticipated by such a measure, and have given very cogent answers to the objections of the opponents, namely:—

Mr. William Cunningham, “Railway Nationalisation.” (Published by himself at Dunfermline, 1906, 2s. 6d.);

Mr. Clement Edwards, M.P., “Railway Nationalisation.” (Methuen & Co., 1907, 2s. 6d.);

and Mr. Emil Davies in several books, including his latest, already referred to, “The Case for Railway Nationalisation.” (Collins, 1913, 1s.)

But in all these books, and in other books and articles, both for and against nationalisation, it has been assumed that if, and when, the railways are acquired by the State, the same system will obtain as now, and as obtains in the case of all the foreign countries and colonies referred to, namely, to charge according to distance and according to “what the traffic will bear,” and with the primary object of making the most profit.

With very great deference to all these distinguished writers, it appears to me that they have one and all overlooked the fundamental principles which should be acted upon by a State or a Municipality first in deciding whether or not to acquire a monopoly, and secondly, in the administration of it when acquired. These principles depend upon the fundamental difference between the objects in view, and actuating a Company or individual on the one hand and a Nation or Municipality on the other in acquiring a monopoly. In the former case the sole object is that of pecuniary gain or profit; in the latter the sole object is, or ought to be, the benefit of the community. It may be said that these are not respectively the sole objects, but only the primary objects. My reply is that in the case of the company it is the duty of the directors, as trustees for the shareholders, to so carry on the business in question as to produce the most profit, irrespective of any benefit to the community, or, indeed, to any persons other than the shareholders. Railway companies, it is true, provide the benefit of transport, and various advantages held out by the companies as inducements to use their particular lines, but these are, of course, solely offered with the view of increasing the profits. Other advantages for the comfort, safety and benefit of the public are provided under compulsion from the Government, as a condition of the grant of privileges and compulsory powers conferred upon the companies, without which the railways could not have been made. I refer to such matters as rules and regulations for the safety and benefit of the public; workmen’s trains; maximum fares and rates allowed to be charged; provision for at least one train a day at all stations, etc.

Conversely, in the case of a Nation or Municipality taking over a monopoly, it is the duty of the Government Department or Town Council to so carry on the business as to render the most efficient service, at the lowest cost consistent with efficiency, with paying for the cost of acquisition and with paying the working expenses. Advocates of nationalisation urge that profits should be applied in reduction of taxation, and suggest that this is in itself one of the benefits to be derived therefrom. Opponents always assume that national and municipal trading must be carried on with a view to profit, and some even ridicule the idea that any trading concern can be successfully carried on unless with this view and with a resulting profit. Acrimonious discussions have taken place as to whether profits which have been claimed by advocates of municipal trading to have been made by tramways, gas, water and electricity works, are only paper profits as alleged by the opponents. In Lord Avebury’s book already referred to,[8] one whole chapter, headed “Loss and Profit,” treats of the question whether municipal enterprises have been profitable or not, and he adduces many examples to prove that in most cases the alleged profits are imaginary.

It has, in fact, been the practice universally to apply profits made out of municipal trading in this Country in reduction of rates, and in foreign Countries, where railways are owned by the State, their revenues are made use of either as general revenue or, as in Prussia, for social or educational purposes, which would otherwise be provided for by direct taxation. The only instance of national trading in this Country is the General Post Office, and I think it is correct to say that the original intention when Penny Post was established was to so carry it on that working expenses only should be covered by the revenue. In practice, the gross revenue is entered with other items of revenue in the National Accounts, and the gross expenditure with other items of general and non-productive expenditure, with the result that the net profits of the Post Office, in effect, become a source of general revenue, and are therefore applied in reduction of general taxation. Until recent years this net profit has not been considerable, but last year it was as much as £5,000,000. Having regard to the continual and progressive increase in postal business, and the acquisition of the whole telephone system, there is every prospect of still further increase in net profits. What will be the result of a continuance of this practice of applying net profits of Municipal and National trading towards reduction of rates and taxes? It has not, so far, had any very serious result, simply on account of the fact that such net profits have not yet been of a very startling amount. But if these profits should increase, will not the result be the very evils which are the natural consequence of a private monopoly?

Once the principle is admitted that profits from such trading shall go in relief of taxation, the service will, and must, be worked more or less with the primary object of making as much profit as possible, with the inevitable result that the service in question will be starved for the sake of the profits. This has actually happened in the case of the Prussian State Railways, the one State Railway which has so far made the greatest net profit.

In addition to this difficulty there are others inherent in State or Municipal trading, if the principle of making profits be admitted, and if profits are actually made. In such a case the Chancellor of the Exchequer will be expected to budget for further profits, the general public will expect improvements in the service, traders will expect that the charges to them should be reduced, and the workers will expect that their wages should be increased.

This view is not a new one. It has been advocated in respect of the Post Office for many years by such well-known postal reformers as Lord Eversley (formerly Mr. Shaw Lefevre), and Sir Henniker Heaton, Bart. The latter, I believe, has several times moved resolutions in the House of Commons for the express purpose of having the postal profit applied to the use of the Post Office itself, instead of to general revenue.

It is well known that “strikes” are more likely to arise in a period of trade prosperity. It is the natural result of the workers seeing large profits made out of their industry, if they should have no benefit, by increase of wages, by sharing in such profits or otherwise. It makes but little difference to the workers that those profits go to ratepayers, instead of to shareholders, more especially as they usually inhabit houses let on weekly inclusive rentals, and are exempt from income-tax, so that they do not directly pay either rates or taxes. If, on the other hand, the profits are devoted to improving the efficiency of the service or cheapening the charges, then, not only are there no profits to excite the cupidity of various sections of the community, but the workers do, in fact, benefit by themselves and their families, as well as the whole of the public for whom the services are worked. No strike is ever successful which does not gain general public support, and even under existing conditions there is much less likelihood of strikes in the case of Civil Servants or postal or municipal employees, partly on account of the better wages paid, the certainty of continuing in employment except for misconduct, and the prospects of a pension, but still more on account of the practical certainty that public support would not be given to a strike which interferes with one of the most important of the public services.[9]

Another evil of ignoring the difference in principle of a public monopoly and a private monopoly has been the practice of applying to public monopolies the practice which all private monopolies endeavour to achieve (and properly so as their sole object is profit), namely, to put down all possible competition. If the principle I advocate, namely, that the sole object of a public monopoly is the benefit of the community, then if some improvement in the service, the subject of such monopoly, shall be invented, which is proved to be practicable, the public should have the benefit of such improvement, and, instead of a prohibition of such private enterprise every encouragement should be given to it.

In our Navy, when new inventions are found which increase its efficiency, no time or money is lost in adopting them, even at the expense of discarding comparatively modern men-of-war or appliances. The risk to the nation of not doing so is too great to allow considerations of expense to stand in the way.

But what has happened in the case of so important a commercial matter as the Telephone? The Post Office are authorised by Act of Parliament to forbid any competition, a provision evidently enacted under the impression that a public monopoly must have Statutory protection against competition, which a private monopoly always seeks to obtain, but has to pay for. Having this monopoly, and having purchased the telegraphs, the Post Office from the first regarded telephones with the utmost jealousy, because it seemed likely to interfere with its “Profits”! Lord Avebury quotes from “The Times” of 13th June, 1884, as follows:—[10]

“… the action of the Post Office has been so directed as to throw every possible difficulty in the way of the development of the telephone, and of its constant employment by the public. We say advisedly, ‘every possible difficulty,’ because the regulations under which licences have been granted to the telephone companies are in many respects as completely prohibitory as an absolute refusal of them.” “… the effects of this claim are nearly as disastrous to the Country as to the inventors and owners of the instruments.”

When it is remembered that the Post Office insisted on being paid one-tenth, not of the profits, but of the gross receipts, the wonder is that our telephone system is not more backward than it is. Lord Avebury, of course, uses this and other instances, such as the opposition of municipalities owning tramway and gas undertakings, to tramway extensions in adjoining districts, and licences to motor omnibuses and also to the introduction of electricity for lighting and power, as an argument against nationalisation and municipal trading.[11] That these constitute a strong argument against public monopolies being worked for profit, I readily admit, but they do not weaken the argument that all such concerns which must, in their very nature, be incapable of effective competition, should be taken over by the community, and be worked solely for its benefit. What possible chance is there of competition in a telephone system? It is, of course, an essential element to its success that each subscriber should be able to communicate with every other one. How, then, can it ever have been imagined that there could be any effective competition between rival systems? And yet competition was actually attempted between various municipalities and the National Telephone Company, and afterwards the Post Office itself was authorised to “compete” with that Company.

The ultimate purchase by the State was, of course, a foregone conclusion, but at what expense of both time and money has this at length been effected! The complaints which have been made since the completion of this purchase are evidently the result, not of nationalisation, but of the mistaken practice followed in a fruitless attempt at making or retaining so-called “profits” of the telegraph system, by at first putting “every possible difficulty” in the way of telephones, then attempting to compete with them, and then waiting a number of years before completing the purchase, with the result of being compelled to take over a large number of obsolete plant and instruments, and linking them up with a new system, thus producing a state of confusion and useless expenditure of time and money, which could all have been avoided by purchase of the patents and patent rights more than 30 years ago.

It is only right to say that Lord Avebury was still of opinion in 1907 that the resolution of the Government to buy up the National Telephone Company was “an extraordinary and most unfortunate policy.”[12]

Mr. Hanbury, who was the Minister mainly responsible in 1906 for the purchase of the telephones, had evidently changed his opinion since 1889, when, in answer to a deputation in favour of purchasing the telephones, he said, according to a report quoted by Lord Avebury from “The Times”:—

“If the telephone service was cast upon the Post Office it would be to the detriment of both the postal and telegraph services. Then, again, it would increase enormously the Government staff. He need only appeal to the Members of Parliament present to say whether they would like to have the weekly appeals for increase of wages from those State servants still further extended.”

Here we have exactly one of the arguments which is now being used against railway nationalisation, and by the very Minister who, 17 years after, did the very thing he had clearly condemned.

I admit the argument would hold good if the restriction be not imposed by an inflexible rule that there should be no attempt to work the concern, whether Post Office, telephone, railway or other monopoly for purposes of profit.

I have already referred to the mistake the Post Office are making in following the example of the private monopolist, the National Telephone Company, in charging for telephones according to distance, although between the very same towns in which different rates are charged the same department charges 6d. only for telegrams! This can only be with the strange, yet futile, intention of making more profit without regard to the benefit of the community. If the same rate were charged for Trunk calls as for local calls, many more provincial and country people would subscribe, and the wires being already laid and exchanges established, the additional expense would be but small.

It would seem, indeed, that the search after profits in the case of Government or municipal monopolies is as futile as the search by people after happiness, personified by Maeterlinck as “The Blue Bird,” and that when the only object is to benefit the community, the profits come, as does happiness, when the only object is that of benefiting other people.

Now, in considering the principle here laid down, it appears to me that there are four rules which should be observed when a nation or municipality undertakes anything in the nature of a trading concern:—

1. Only such concerns should be taken over as are, and must be, in the very nature of things, a monopoly, or, in other words, are not susceptible of effective competition.

2. Any such concern taken over should be worked with the sole object in view of benefiting the community and, therefore, the charges made should be so adjusted as to pay for the acquisition of the concern and for working expenses, and any surplus from time to time applied, only in improving the efficiency of the undertaking, or in reducing the charges made.

3. In the event of any invention or improvement being made, and proved to be commercially successful, whereby the benefit to the community can be increased, and provided the concern remains in its nature a monopoly, such improvements should be taken over and worked by the State or municipality, and meantime there should be no prohibition of any private enterprise carried on in competition apparent or real.

4. All such concerns, whether national or municipal, should be worked or directed by one or more Department of State, having at its head a Minister, who should be a Member of the Cabinet, and responsible to the House of Commons, and as such liable to a vote of censure for any abuse or want of efficiency in the concern.

As to Rule No. 1, there appears sometimes to be a very thin line between what is, and is not, susceptible of effective competition. As a general rule, any concern which involves a right or easement over land, must be in the nature of a monopoly. Thus the supply of gas, water and electricity, all of which must be conveyed by pipes or wires into houses, are in the nature of a monopoly, but the fittings used in the houses are not, but are susceptible of very efficient competition, both as to workmanship, manufacture and design. All roads, including railroads and tramways, are, and must be, in the nature of a monopoly, but the manufacture of materials and rolling stock, the catering of hotels, forming part of the railway undertakings, or in the trains themselves, or in railway steamers, are all the subject of effective competition and should, therefore, be put up for competition with special supervision and restrictions against abuse of the privileges obtained by competition on Government property.

Now, I would ask any unprejudiced reader who has studied the writings of the eminent authors already quoted, and other opponents of nationalisation, to read those books again with these four rules in his mind, and consider whether all the objections so forcibly brought forward against nationalisation would not be very nearly, if not completely, answered, if such nationalisation were carried out with strict adherence to these rules.

I venture to think that Lord Avebury himself would have admitted the force of this contention. It would, at least, answer the question he puts more than once, “Where, indeed, is it (municipal and national trading) to stop? Is it to stop at all?… It is sometimes said that the line should be drawn at necessaries. But if so, to light, gas, water and tramways, we should have to add bread, meat, fire insurance, … etc., while many would also add tobacco, tea and beer.”[13]

In effect, the whole of the objections to State ownership, as will appear from a perusal of the various books referred to above, and the arguments of other opponents, are all comprised under three heads, namely, according to the relationship of the State:—

1. With traders.

2. With railway servants.

3. With the general public, especially on such matters as officialism and inefficiency, owing to want of competition, bad administration, and interference with private enterprise.

The first of the two objections referred to is that the Government would be in the great difficulty of having to meet the conflicting interests of traders and merchants on the one hand, and the general public on the other, with continual disputes as to the claims of various parties, and possible attempts to bring influence to bear on the Government and Members of Parliament. This objection was raised by the Prime Minister recently in reply to a deputation supporting railway nationalisation. The difficulty has been found in countries where railways are State owned, and would, I admit, be a most serious objection, if, after nationalisation, the railways should be worked on the same principle as now, namely, with the object of making the most profit possible, and charging according to “what the traffic will bear.”

The objection, however, disappears if the proposed rules are adhered to, especially when, as in the proposed scheme, fares and rates are fixed irrespective of distance, locality, class of traders or goods, and in which, therefore, no question of preference or, indeed, of any conflicting interests can arise.

As to the second heading, affecting the relationship of the State with the railway servants. It is suggested that the railway servants (who would, on nationalisation, become Civil servants) could use their voting powers to exact undue privileges for themselves which they cannot now obtain, and that serious abuses might arise owing to the great political power exercised by a large increase in the number of voters who are also Civil servants.

This does not appear to me so formidable an objection as the first, but it is quite possible that a large united body of Civil servants might have power to so influence the Government as to extract higher wages or less hours, if they discovered that by their exertions a very large profit was derived by the railway system.

Some writers have gone so far as to suggest that all persons employed by Government should be disfranchised. Others suggest that special representatives of Government officials should be returned to Parliament. Others that all such officials should take the same oath of allegiance as soldiers, and, in short, become subject to military discipline. In two articles appearing recently in the “Westminster Gazette,” under the title of “Unrest in the Railway World, by an Expert,”[14] it is suggested that “unless some discipline of the military kind were introduced” (in the event of nationalisation), “there would be no available methods of dealing with a national strike of railwaymen, other than to concede to their demands.” The question of “Strikes” has already been dealt with above (page 36). As to the political difficulty, although it is true that the number of Civil servants would be greatly increased (and it has been estimated that the total number of postal and railway servants who would have the vote might be as many as 600,000), it must be remembered, as pointed out by Mr. Emil Davies, that this number is spread over the whole Country, and the percentages in each district, compared to the whole number of voters, would not be a large one, except in railway centres like Crewe, where they already have a preponderance of votes. In any case, the same considerations which, as above mentioned, would be likely to prevent strikes, would operate equally in the region of politics if the four rules mentioned are adhered to, especially under the proposed scheme, carried on with the primary object of the public benefit. Exactly the same conditions would obtain as with the Post Office now.

Other grounds of objection to State ownership are:—

1. The fear of inefficiency owing to lack of competition.

2. The fear of difficulty in obtaining redress for loss or injury from a Government Department.

3. The fear of officialism.

As to competition, it is now generally admitted that there is no effective competition on railways.[15] In most parts of the country there never has been any competition, as one company only is available. In others, where more than one company operates, working arrangements have been made not only as to the fares and rates but also as to time of trains, thus precluding any effective competition. In the very nature of things no competition can be effective in a system of railway transit.

As to the questions of officialism and difficulties of obtaining redress, can anyone suggest that these are less in the case of private companies, responsible to no one but themselves, than in the case of a Government Department with a Cabinet Minister at the head who is responsible to Parliament? A vote of censure is one of the most powerful weapons in Constitutional countries against any serious abuse in a Government Department.

Mr. Edwin A. Pratt, in his book before referred to, cannot but admit the cogency of the argument in favour of the amalgamation and unification of the railways, but urges that this should be accomplished by the amalgamation of the whole of the existing railways into a Trust or Traffic Board. The answer to this is that when once constituted, even though appointed by Parliament, such a Board is responsible to no one but itself, and, however eminent may be the directors or managers, the want of ultimate responsibility inevitably and unconsciously leads to abuses. Can any instance be adduced of the successful working of any such large Trust or Board? On the other hand, instances are well known to the contrary. One of these was the notorious Metropolitan Board of Works. And is it certain that the Metropolitan Water Board and the Port of London Authority, both of which are constituted on similar lines, will answer all the expectations which were formed of them?

There are, of course, difficulties inherent in the administration of a great Government Department, but, as already hinted, various remedies may be suggested for many of these difficulties. For instance, there might be elected a Railway Council or Standing Committee in Parliament, consisting of representatives of several large districts of the United Kingdom, and of which the “Minister of Transport” would be, ex-officio, the President. In the first instance possibly some of the present directors of railway companies, many of whom are already in Parliament, could be members of this Council. Any proposals for improvements, extensions or alterations in the services of the railway or Post Office would be submitted to and decided upon by this Council or Committee, subject to an appeal to Parliament on questions of principle or finance. This would be one means of obviating an objection found in some countries where the railways are owned by the State, namely, the continual trivial complaints made in Parliament about the railways.

A further suggestion is that a special Railway Court should be established in London with branches in every important centre, and presided over by competent arbitrators to determine and adjudicate upon claims against the Department for personal injuries to passengers and servants, or for loss of or damage to goods, or by reason of delay, any one accident, involving a large number of claims, being dealt with by the same Court instead of being, as now, the subject of innumerable actions at law in the ordinary Courts. This Railway Court might also be useful in settling disputes between the Government and the men.

OTHER OBJECTIONS.

Apart from the objection to State ownership there are no doubt many who are now deriving income from railways who will fear that their interests may be prejudiced by the proposed change. Fortunately there can be but very few who will be thus prejudiced. As to the existing staffs, such as booking clerks and the Railway Clearing House staff, whose services would no longer be required in those particular departments, there ought to be more than sufficient vacancies for these in other but more necessary branches of the railway service, especially in view of the increased traffic which is sure to arise.

Many traders who may at first sight consider that their profits would suffer if the scheme is adopted will find on further consideration that the benefits they will have by the proposed scheme will be greater than any loss they could possibly sustain. To take one instance. Newspaper proprietors may consider that upon railways being nationalised they would lose the benefit of the extensive and remunerative advertisements they now receive from competing railway companies. So far from there being any loss, there will be profits, partly by the official announcements which the Department will cause to be inserted in all newspapers of time tables, rates, etc., but even more so by the enormous saving in the carriage of paper and of the newspapers, in travelling expenses of special correspondents and others, and by the additional profits arising from increased circulation which is sure to follow upon the increased facility and cheapness of distribution.

Mr. W. M. Acworth, the well-known railway expert, to whom I submitted a rough draft of this pamphlet, was kind enough, while refraining from any detailed criticism, to call my attention to what he considered a difficulty in my proposals. He says:

“The fundamental objection to a scheme of average fares and rates is that people whose fares and goods rates are ‘averaged up’ will, so far as possible, cease to use the trains; those whose fares and rates are ‘averaged down’ will increase enormously, with a corresponding increase in working expenses. Have you appreciated that under your scheme a passenger from London to Glasgow would, in fact, in most cases pay, not 1s., but 3d. or 4d., by taking local tickets from London to Birmingham, Birmingham to Crewe, etc?”

And he instances the Hungarian zone system, which has completely broken down, as a case in point.

My answer to this is, first, that according to my scheme there is no “averaging up;” the flat fares are all “averaged down” to the minimum. Secondly, while welcoming the admission that the effect of “averaging down” is to increase the traffic “enormously,” I am sure that Mr. Acworth himself does not mean that the working expenses will increase in anything like the same proportion. He has himself pointed out in an article on railways[16] that the train cost of carrying 200 passengers and 10 passengers is practically the same. Further reasons for this fact are given under the heading of “Working Expenses” in this pamphlet. Thirdly, while admitting that under my scheme a passenger might, by taking three local trains which stop at all stations travel from London to Glasgow for 3d., I can hardly imagine that any but the smallest percentage of travellers would endeavour to save 9d. by taking a journey in which they would spend sixteen hours and have two changes at least, instead of travelling the same distance by one train, in eight hours, for 1s. As to the zone system, the whole advantage of the flat rate or uniform fare is lost by the difficulty of passing from one zone to the other.

FOOTNOTES

[6] “On Municipal and National Trading” by The Rt. Hon. Lord Avebury. Published by Macmillan & Co., 1907. Price 2/6.

[7] “The Case Against Railway Nationalisation” by Edwin A. Pratt. Published by Collins, 1913. Price 1/-.

[8] “On Municipal and National Trading,” pp. 56-92.

[9] While this pamphlet has been in the Press, there has been a strike of the Leeds Municipal workers, and the threat of a strike in the Post Office. It will be interesting to see whether the considerations above mentioned under existing conditions will be borne out, and still more if when the causes are ascertained, it can be proved that had the principles here advocated been carried out in practice, there would have been no strike, nor any threat of one.

[10] On Municipal and National Trading, p. 109.

[11] Ibid, Chapter VII.

[12] On Municipal and National Trading, p. 107.

[13] “On Municipal and National Trading,” page 10.

[14] “Westminster Gazette” of December 2nd, 1913.

[15] See “The Railways of Great Britain” by Lord Monkswell. (Smith, Elder & Co., 1913. Price 6/-). A most interesting book, published since this pamphlet was written.—Lord Monkswell is not an advocate of nationalisation, but apparently has an open mind.—He admits that England is now only served by five groups of railways, and that there is no effective competition.

[16] In Palgrave’s “EncyclopÆdia of Political Economy,” Vol. III. (1899), Article on Railways, signed W.M.A.


                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                           

Clyx.com


Top of Page
Top of Page